Post-Autistic Economics Network
Home Page
PAE
Review
|
www.paecon.net
from post-autistic economics newsletter :
issue no. 6, May, 2001
The Relevance of
Controversies for Practice as Well as Teaching
Sheila C Dow (University of Stirling)
One of the important PAE arguments put forward by Raveaud
in the March 2001
Newsletter (‘Teaching Economics
Through Controversies’) is that economics should be
taught in terms of controversies instead of as an agreed body of thought. In
effect this
means teaching the dynamic development of ideas over time, i.e., a historical
approach,
since controversies involve sequential developments. If theory is
context-dependent, then
we can learn much, not only from controversies among contemporaries in
different contexts,
but also from controversies between economists working within different
contexts in history.
Controversies reveal a range of possible ways of theorising about the
economy, drawing out
the different understandings of the subject matter, the different meanings
attached to the
same terms and the different methodologies employed. By getting a sense of
the range of
possibilities, students can develop the capacity for judgement necessary for
deciding how
best to develop theory to address future contexts.
But what is the role of controversy for the practising economist? It is
perhaps helpful to think
of controversy in terms of Kuhn’s paradigm framework. Each paradigm is
pursued by a
community of economists who share foundations, in terms of understanding of
reality,
meaning of terms, methodological approach, and so on. There is considerable
scope for
controversy between paradigms in that each will approach similar problems
quite differently.
There is also much scope for talking at cross purposes, since the nature of
the problem
may be understood quite differently, similar methods may be part of very
different
methodologies, and similar terms may have very different meanings. In other
words,
paradigms are incommensurate; there is no neutral ground on which to stand.
Kuhn made
of agreed methods within the paradigm. The significant controversies are the
province of
extraordinary science, which puts the focus on the foundations of
paradigms.
If most economists are likely to engage in normal science, then, what is the
relevance of
controversies which refer to fundamentals? First, the Kuhnian
framework is helpful for
putting the focus on the scope for incommensurability between paradigms, but
requires
careful consideration when applied to a discipline like economics where there
are
coexisting paradigms. Kuhn’s framework originally referred to the physical
sciences,
in terms of succeeding paradigms. In economics the paradigms have never been
mutually-
exclusive; it has simply been helpful to think in terms of the clear
differences between
‘representative members’ of different paradigms. Increasingly there are
efforts to promote
synthesis, particularly between heterodox paradigms, thus blurring the
distinctions.
Synthesis of course means the emergence of new paradigms, but the picture of
what will
emerge is not yet clear. Within orthodox economics also there have been
developments
which call attention to fundamentals; but here the developments are more ones
of
fragmentation than synthesis.
In the current state of flux in economics, therefore, extraordinary science
comes to the
fore. In order to make sense of these processes of synthesis and
fragmentation, it is
important to be aware of the foundations of new theory developments. Indeed
it could be
argued that those developments in economic theory which have proved pivotal
have arisen
at the margins of paradigms, within extraordinary science. New developments
in thought
can always be traced back to some extent to previous history of thought
(within some
paradigm), but at the same time require new connections to be made and new
meanings
to be employed. A prerequisite for such a development is exposure to
different possible
approaches. This is an argument for methodological awareness, which can be
most
effectively acquired through engagement with controversies past and present.
Without
such awareness, which promotes alertness to differences in understanding,
methodology
and meaning, the different protagonists in controversies will be
misunderstood and
opportunities for new connections lost. As James Galbraith points out in his
contribution
to the January 2001 Newsletter, there is a notable lack of awareness within
orthodox
economics of the challenges it faces.
The argument for methodological awareness as a prerequisite for engagement
has most
force in periods, such as the present, when economics is in a particular
state of flux.
But what about more stable periods? Methodological awareness can be promoted
by
study of past controversies. But there is a second case for methodological
awareness
which is different, in that it rests more heavily on the benefits of
tolerance. Tolerance
means allowing a range of approaches to develop to maturity, so that, when
new challenges
arise, there is a diversity from which ideas may be selected (just as in
biology diversity is
important for adaptation and survival). When a discipline is stable, there is
a danger of
thinking of the dominant paradigm as being not just preferred by the majority,
but as being
preferable in some absolute, extra-paradigmatic, sense. Such a state of
affairs can breed
intolerance to any other paradigm. Not only does this limit the scope of the
dominant
paradigm, but also it encourages institutionalised constraints on alternative
paradigms.
There is further an asymmetry in that paradigms which adopt a methodology
unified around
mathematical formalism applied to a shared set of axioms (as in orthodox
economics) are
more likely to have a closed-system theory of knowledge than paradigms which
embrace
some form of pluralism. But without some prior knowledge of pluralism it is
hard to see how
the judgement in favour of a monist (i.e., anti-pluralist) methodology can be
justified. It is a
matter of choice as to the methodology we employ in order to understand a
complex reality.
No one methodology can reasonably claim any absolute superiority, yet choices
have to be
made for policy issues to be addressed. But no one approach can be justified
relative to
the others without an informed comparison.
We have come back full circle to the value of a pluralist education in
economics.
SUGGESTED CITATION:
Sheila C. Dow (2001) “The Relevance of
Controversies for Practice as Well as Teaching”, post-autistic economics
newsletter : issue no. 6, May, article 5.
http://www.btinternet.com/~pae_news/review/issue6.htm
|