post-autistic
economics review |
issue 25
contents
PAE
Review index
home page |
The
American Economic Problem* At
present writing in early 2004, nearly nine million Americans remain
unemployed. Millions more are underemployed, and most of all, underpaid.
Forty-four million lack health insurance. Our schools, colleges,
universities, roads, water systems, power lines are in decay – and the funds
required to repair and expand them are being cut. Not least, we are in a war
with no end in sight. That is our economic problem. George Bush did not entirely create this
problem. The late 1990s were a moment of genuine prosperity and that rarest
of economic achievements, full employment. But they were based on dreams,
illusions and mortgages. The bubble in high technology, the rise in
inequality, the debt build-up of American households, the squeeze on public
investment, Al Qaeda – these existed before we got George Bush. Mr. Bush’s essential contribution has been to
make the problem harder to fix. The 2001 and 2003 tax cuts flowed,
notoriously, to the very wealthy, who do not repair power lines and whose
spending is little affected by extra income. Meanwhile middle-class and
working Americans faced property and sales tax increases at the state and
local level, alongside drastic cuts in education and health services. Team
Bush is bent on eroding pay and working conditions, as in their recent
assault on fair labor standards affecting overtime. Possibly, this is intentional. The men in charge
under George Bush talk about growth. Certainly they appreciate the positive
growth rates that war spending has brought them. But do they really want full
employment prosperity, strong labor unions and
rising wages? Probably not. The oil, mining, defense,
media and drug firms who form their constituency rely on monopoly power,
patents, and the control of public resources for their profits. They are
threatened by strong labor and do not depend, very
much, on strong consumer demand. Stagnation, moreover, will help to justify even
more tax reduction. The administration’s core policy objective in this area
is the simple distributive goal that financial wealth should, eventually, be
freed of tax. In 2001 estate and income taxes were cut. In 2003 it was
capital gains, dividends and again the top tax rate. In 2004, if plans are
followed, the sunset provisions in these measures will be removed. As things
are going, quite soon, federal taxes will fall mainly on payrolls and on
current consumption. Such taxes are paid mostly by the middle class, by the
working class and by the poor. Stagnation also promotes plans to cut essential
services, including health, education and pensions. As financial wealth
escapes tax, neither states, nor cities, nor the federal government can
provide vital services on their own – except by taxing sales and property at
rates that will provoke tax rebellions, especially when middle class incomes
are not rising. Every public service will fall between the hammer of tax cuts
and the anvil of deficits in state, local, and federal budgets. The streets
will be dirtier, as also the air, and the water. Emergency rooms will back up
even more than they have; more doctors will refuse public patients. More fire
houses and swimming pools and libraries will be closed. Public universities
will cost more; the public schools will lose the middle class. Eventually –
and perhaps as soon as the year following the election – federal budget
deficits will collide with Social Security and Medicare, putting
privatization back on the agenda. In the near term, more military spending – the
Iraq war, the occupation and military restocking – and the portion of the tax
cuts that did flow to the middle class are bringing what may perhaps best be described
as a false dawn. Indeed in 2003 we again learned two Keynesian truths. First,
that a big increase in government spending is a fast and efficient way to
pump up the economic growth rate. Second, that most households are
income-constrained; increasing their disposable income will increase their
spending. But the future tax cuts are weighted even more heavily to the
wealthy, and the pace of military spending is unstable and in any event
unsatisfactory way to generate an enduring economic expansion. The Federal Reserve Chairman, Alan Greenspan, has
done his best to keep the American housing bubble blown up, through low and
stable interest rates. But not even Mr. Greenspan can forever prevent bubbles
from popping, and eventually the housing boom will reach its climax. Big
deficits and easy money, though necessary, will not, by themselves, bring
full employment. Because of the damage already done, no matter who
takes office in 2005, full, effective and sustainable economic recovery for
America will be difficult. It will not be merely a matter of spending more,
of »stimulus« – an ugly metaphor that falsely depicts full recovery as a
one-shot affair and reminds most people of a hypodermic stick. It will not be
a mere matter of finding the right taxes to cut – or to increase. It will
certainly not be a simple matter of balancing the budget. Rather, full recovery will require understanding
needs and designing and implementing programs to meet them, both at home and
in the international sphere. It will be truly a matter of new departures.
Along the way, it will be a matter of overcoming the obstacles left by the
legacy of the late 1990s and compounded by the present administration. These obstacles include excess capacity and
depressed expectations, which affect the future of business investment. This
will not last indefinitely; in due course the overbuilding of the late 1990s
in telecommunications and other sectors will cease to matter. But this will
remain a problem for some considerable time yet. There is also the fact that the reputation of
American financial markets has been damaged by fraud and abuse, by a
corporate crime wave. Many believe that law enforcement in this area by the
Justice Department and Securities and Exchange Commission have been
compromised by a political fact – namely, the prevalence of criminal
practices among companies with close ties to Mr. Bush. Enron, whose CEO was one of Mr. Bush’s largest contributors, is only
the most notable example. This perception may impede the enduring recovery of
asset values, or perhaps the value of the dollar itself – though no one can
say to what extent. Low interest rates, tax rebates, and increased
military spending have kept households afloat so far. The ultimate barrier to
household debt acquisition is the ability to pay interest, and so far this
has not reached the crisis point. Mortgages have continued to be refinanced,
and debt has continued to grow. That households were willing to take on more
debt than anyone could have foreseen has kept the slowdown from being far
more severe. But while this is good news for the present, it is bad news for
the future. It remains the case that what cannot go on forever will
eventually stop. The potential therefore remains for a substantial
future deceleration in household spending. Consumer spending is over
sixty percent of national income, and the pace at which households increase
their spending is a key determinant of the pace of economic expansion
overall. If and as household spending decelerates, then large increases in
the other major, but much smaller, components of spending – government,
business investment, and net exports – are necessary to keep the economy
growing. And a consumer deceleration would be much aggravated by increasing
interest rates, which might even convert a deceleration into an actual
decline in total spending, at least for a short period of time. Conversely, for household spending actually to
lead a recovery, household debt would have to resume its rise in relation
to household income. Such a turn of events would be normal at some stage
in most recoveries, when initial debt ratios are lower. But under current
conditions it seems unlikely, and if it does occur, it probably will not
endure for very long. The basic reality is that the boom of the 1990s created
conditions that were highly abnormal, and therefore the path of
recovery is likely to be abnormal as well – abnormally weak and abnormally
fragile. The other big problem going forward is America’s
very weak position in foreign trade. We have a propensity, now deeply
entrenched, to run very large foreign deficits at full employment. This is
the product of a witches’ brew of international economic factors: the high
dollar over many years, the decline of the financial system supporting
international economic development, and the erosion of parts of our own
manufacturing base. Given this structural weakness, extra purchasing power
leaks abroad and it is all the more difficult to reach full employment. In sum, so long as households, businesses and
also state and local governments are still retrenching, an expansion
sufficient to generate return to full employment would require one of two
improbable events. Either federal budget deficits must rise by a
phenomenal further amount – probably to somewhere between eight hundred
billion and a trillion dollars annually. Or, in the alternative, the
U. S. must find a way to increase exports and reduce imports relative to GDP,
thus making it possible for a smaller budget deficit to do the job on
domestic employment. Can the now-fallen dollar square this circle,
giving us lower foreign deficits and so reducing the need for fiscal
expansion? It appears unlikely. On one side, estimates of the price
elasticity of American exports suggest that a lower dollar will not increase
European demand for American products by leaps and bounds. On the other side,
U. S. consumer goods imports come very substantially from countries (such as
Mexico and China) against whose currencies the dollar has not declined, and
who are prepared to suffer considerable hardship to prevent such a decline,
in order to maintain their present access to the U.S. market. Therefore these
imports are not becoming markedly more expensive and the demand for them is
unlikely to be choked off by considerations of cost. Things could change on
their own: American households might tire of cheap clothing, athletic shoes
and electronic toys. But given how much these items contribute to the modest
comforts of working class American life, this also seems very unlikely. Further, one may doubt the willingness of the
Treasury and Federal Reserve to tolerate a declining dollar – even one that
is falling only against the euro – for an indefinite period. At some point,
considerations of national pride will be raised, Latin American debtors may
default and U.S. banks may begin to object to the erosion of their
international position. A dollar defense, if
effected by raising interest rates, would of course only make the domestic
position much worse. This will not happen before the election, but afterward
it is a possibility. The baseline outlook then is not one where
a return to full employment prosperity is likely to be achieved on the
current course, nor by small policy changes. Pushing a few well-chosen
buttons in the tax code will not do it, however desirable pushing such
buttons may be on other grounds. And the Federal Reserve has largely run out
of magic tricks, however much its officials may hint otherwise. The baseline
outlook is for a period of strong growth immediately before the election and
stagnation afterward – just as the administration anyhow prefers. Any new
administration, committed to a better economic result, will have to be prepared
with strong measures, capable of changing the underlying macro-dynamic. To round out the current economic picture, we
need to consider the world outside. To the Bush administration, the world
outside is mainly a supplier. Cheap labor and cheap
oil are the mainstays of the administration’s external policy, so far as it
has a clear economic dimension (extra soldiers and contributions to military
campaigns are also required from time to time). Cooperation, national
development and mutual gain are no longer high on the external agenda, which
means that many export markets in which U. S. firms have a strong comparative
advantage (for example, electronics, telecommunications, and aerospace) are
not flourishing. This represents a failure of vision and strategy on the
international economic front. The inevitable fact is, as we pursue a policy of
attack and control overseas, we are acquiring an empire – consisting so far
of Afghanistan and Iraq, with smaller garrisons in place in numerous other
places. The difficulty of empire is that it is expensive
in material and moral terms. In Iraq, for a very brief period, the
administration pretended that a vast country could be governed from the
outside by a skeleton crew, consisting mainly of very young soldiers, trained
well for combat but poorly for civil administration in an Arabic-speaking
country. The provision of security, infrastructure and civil administration
was not adequately prepared for. Instead, the administration has chosen to
pursue a version of »shock therapy« – of conversion to unregulated private
markets – that would have seemed extreme even to the market Bolsheviks of the
collapsing Soviet Union in 1991. Meanwhile the burdens of empire are growing
palpably as time passes. While success against the Iraqi resistance remains
possible, it is also possible that the U. S. will be forced eventually to
choose between leaving Iraq or putting in the full force required to control
and to run it. One way we lose control, while the other can only add to the miseries
of our balance of payments, while forcing the mobilization of hundreds of
thousands of young Americans into military and occupation service and
exposing them to a high level of violence. In such a contest, the local
adversary has great advantages, including considerable cover among the local
population and access to cheap and effective means of resistance, including
explosives, mines, automatic rifles and rocket-propelled grenades. How can the cost be met, especially, if the coin
of our realm, the U. S. dollar, is at the same time vulnerable? It may not be
impossible, but it won’t be easy. The problem of empires, historically, is
not military defeat. It is bankruptcy: moral, political, and also economic. Empires do not tend to business at home, and they
tend to lose out to rivals who do. Investments made in distant places are
sunk; once the empire ends they bring no more benefit to the country that
bore the cost. By contrast, investments made at home accumulate and yield a
return for centuries into the future. Although Europe faces formidable
problems of economic governance, it is not too difficult to foresee a day
when this difference in current behavior will give
Europe an economic advantage over the United States. There is irony here for America’s
wealthy. It is true that a group of great wealth holds the levers of power in
the country today. But this group, in large measure a coalition of
contractors and monopolists, does not have interests in common with the full
range of wealthy individuals in this wealthy land. There are many others –
exporters, retailers, the residents of large cities, providers of services to
the broad population and many passive investors – whose interests align with
those of working Americans and who would prosper even more under an economy
investing vigorously at home. They are not well served by a program of stagnation and
empire, even partially compensated by tax cuts on capital income. Ultimately, nations prosper or decline as
a unit. An economy that fails for working Americans cannot work for the
wealthy either. While the Bush administration may leave wealthy individuals
relatively untaxed, they will not escape from it as rich, as comfortable, or
as secure as they were before. Already their stocks are off by trillions,
reflecting the diminished outlook for their business holdings. Soon it may be
their houses as well as those of the middle class. If and as the dollar
declines, it will be their cash holdings. If they choose to lend their
children to the tasks of empire, they will lose a few. And if they don’t, it
is certain that those actually doing the fighting will remember who did, and
who did not, contribute to that burden. Ultimately there will be political
consequences from that choice, as from all the others. * This article appears in the current issue of the new journal Intervention:
Journal of Economics, whose editors have kindly given permission for its
republication here. The first issue of
Intervention may be downloaded for free at
http://www.zeitschrift-intervention.de
and http://www.journal-intervention.org. ______________________________ |