post-autistic
economics review |
|
issue 20
contents
PAE
Review index
home page |
|
Is GDP a good measure of economic progress?*
|
|
The arguments presented
above cast doubt on the usefulness of GDP as the main “pilot” of economic
policy. If the thermometer is wrong, then the policy based on it should be wrong
too. The use of GDP produces biases in favour of a particular set of
political choices, consisting in marketisation of
economic activity. This also means that international comparisons based on
GDP are fundamentally flawed. In two ways, following the two problems
associated with GDP:
-
two
countries with different levels of “marketisation”
cannot be compared on the basis of GDP, as GDP will not include the same
activities in the two countries (part of economic activity will be excluded
from the comparison);
-
two
countries with different levels of destruction cannot be compared on the
basis of GDP as these very destructions are not taken into account. Peaceful
societies, characterised by a lower level of crime (and consequently legal
activities, private prisons, etc.) are penalised in terms of GDP! As are
countries with a healthy way of life!
And all this is without
even taking into account the technical difficulties: how to compare GDPs
measured in different currencies? If we use simple exchange rates, we run the
risk to have very volatile results (the euro lost 30% of its value against
the dollar from January 1999 to October 2000, but it would have been stupid
to conclude that GDP dropped in the same proportion). The purchasing power
parity method, used by economists to take into account the fact that
currencies do not buy the same amount of goods and services, is not without
problems, too. Is it relevant to compare the price of the same basket of
goods and services in different countries (to derive purchasing powers) when
the structures of the studied economies vary. Finally, statistical methods
used to measure outputs and prices differ significantly across the world.
Thus, cross-country comparisons create many more difficulties than the
already problematic national GDP calculation.
Paradoxically, it is mostly
for poor countries that alternatives to standard GDP have been developed,
though they are badly needed for rich countries too. For instance, the United
Nations Development Programme (UNDP) calculates a
Human Development Index (HDI), which includes GDP
per capita, but also the literacy rate, life expectancy at birth and school
enrolment ratios. A report to the French ministry for Social Economy
(abolished by the current government) suggested that the human development
report (now limited to poor regions) be extended to cover Europe. Others have
tried to build more relevant measures of GDP, by removing from standard GDP
values added that do not increase well-being or that contribute to the
destruction of natural resources, and by adding domestic and voluntary work.
One such example is the Genuine Progress Indicator, calculated by the US NGO
Redefining Progress (see above) for the US, and which has been stagnating
since the early 1980s (while standard GDP almost doubled over the same
period).
Yet, these interesting
experiments are not without drawbacks : besides numerous technical
difficulties, similar to those identified for the measure of standard GDP,
the choice to include or exclude economic activities from the new index can
easily be arbitrary. For instance, should we exclude health care linked to
avoidable diseases on the ground that it merely reflects a fundamentally
unhealthy way of life (the counterpart of other parts of GDP such as
fast-food activities, or tobacco, so as not to be counted twice…). Or should
we include it because it makes people live better, everything else being equal…? Should we exclude legal activities
linked to divorces because divorce is a sad thing which reflects the
disintegration of families in contemporary societies, or include them as they
allow women to enjoy more independence?
In my opinion, we should
give up trying to compete in terms of GDP (an aggregated indicator). Economic
development is always something with many dimensions. Therefore, an economic
system should be judged on its ability to provide individuals with what they
need to achieve well-being : food, health, leisure, clean air, a high life
expectancy, means of communication, etc. For each of these sub-categories, it
is possible to build indicators that reflect to what extent the population
enjoys access to these resources. Not an average indicator but one that takes
inequality into account : two people with a phone each is better than one
people with two phones and one without any. Thus, we would be able (in fact
we already are, but these figures are never publicized) to compare two
countries by comparing their ability to provide these essential goods to the
largest possible part of their population. We would certainly have some
surprises, such as that the World Health Organisation ranks the US health
system as 37th in the world, while France ranks 1st and
Portugal 12th, two countries with a much lower GDP per capita.
*This article originally
appeared in Les Éconoclastes, Petit breviaire des idées reçues en économie, Paris: Éditions la découverte, 2003.
______________________________
SUGGESTED CITATION:
Olivier Vaury, “Is GDP a good measure of economic progress?“, post-autistic
economics review, issue no. 20,
3 June 2003, article 3, http://www.paecon.net/PAEReview/issue20/Vaury20.htm