post-autistic economics review
Issue no. 20, 3 June 2003
article 4

 

 

      issue 20 contents                            PAE Review index                               home page

 

 

 

Economics: The Disappearing Science?*

Alan Shipman

© Copyright 2003 Alan Shipman

 

 

Economics can easily explain the demise of wheelwrights, weavers and wallpaper hangers. Technical progress dispelled the first group, globalisation the second, changing preferences the third. 

 

The ‘dismal science’ has more difficulty accounting for its own disappearance. But the downtrend in UK economics has now persisted too long to be dismissed as a mere correction after momentary excess.

 

Entry of home students to PhD courses has fallen to “dangerously low levels” according to Royal Economic Society research published in 2000. Two of the country’s most prestigious institutions (London School of Economics and Nuffield College, Oxford) had, that year, attracted no new UK doctoral students. Demand for national funds to support these had also slumped to the level of supply, while sociology and politics maintained their usual over-subscription.

 

The Royal Economic Society gives a predictably economic explanation for the flight from higher degrees. “Relatively low pay and unattractive working conditions in academia” persuade high-flyers to seek higher returns on their instructional investment. Writing before stock markets stumbled, report authors Stephen Machin and Andrew Oswald noted that City economists could earn up to five times their academic counterparts, with senior management, consultancy and civil service jobs also catapulting more basically qualified economists above the professors who taught them. At Oswald’s Warwick University, the proportion of first-class honours students staying on for further study dropped from 80% in 1983-5 to 33% by 1995-7.

 

But if this were the only explanation for decline, demand for more basic economic qualifications would have held up. In reality, the PhD numbers plunge is the culmination of a fall in interest all along the economist production line.. Shrinking UK postgraduate entry results from steady decline in undergraduate and taught masters interest, now mirrored in the final pre-university  years. Entries for economics A-level slid from over 32,000 in 1993/4 to less than 20,000 in 2000/01.

 

The American Economic Association has dug more deeply for explanations of its own declining undergraduate enrolments, which peaked in 1990. American Economics Association research suggests this is due not just to doubts on the economic rewards of staying the course, but disillusionment with the way it is structured and taught. From being a historical and literary subject, whose journals could still be understood by non-specialists into the 1960s, the subject’s ‘mainstream’ research has become submerged in mathematical modelling and statistical analysis.  A shift in assessment methods from essays to exercises and multiple choice tests further opens the subject to mathematicians who have never read the economic ‘classics’, while closing it to those who study nothing else. 

 

By ‘formalising’ past ideas into highly stylised models, economics has become a narrow problem-solving exercise, denying students the big picture they expect it to provide. With dialogue confined to a shrinking range of specialists familiar with the same formulae, the subject’s past power to clarify everyday dilemmas has if anything been reversed. “Many college seniors who have taken an economics course still show a lack of understanding of basic economics,” laments the latest American Economics Association survey of economic literacy by William Wallstad and Sam Allgood, echoing recent British results. Though adept at deducing a rational agent’s optimum consumption bundle, new graduates are often baffled by practical questions - what happens when an exchange rate falls, who sets monetary policy, or what can be done to fend off a recession.

 

Detachment from reality is especially a deterrent for women and ethnic minorities, whose second-class status is confirmed in other Royal Economic Society surveys. In the UK women comprise one-third of PhD candidates and hold almost the same proportion of fixed-term lecturers in economics, but hold only 17% of permanent lectureships, and 4% of professorships. Although family-unfriendly faculties are part of the explanation, the earnings gap for unmarried women (14% below male counterparts) is actually greater than that for married women (‘only’ 9%). Similar discrimination was found for ethnic minority economists, who on average earned 8% less than white counterparts, even after adjusting for their relatively greater youth and resultant shorter experience and publication records.

 

Reviewing these millennial results, Royal Economic Society president Partha Dasgupta and women’s committee chair Carol Propper looked across the Atlantic for salvation, inferring from a strong PhD market that “clearly US economics continues to generate innovation and intellectual excitement.” When, as end-century chair of the Cambridge economics faculty, Dasgupta led a radical redesign of its undergraduate course, he had little hesitation in swapping ‘Cambridge Tradition’ for the North American approach.

 

Cambridge’s new course, whose final phasing-in this year will coincide with the hundredth anniversary of the original, downgrades Keynesian demand deficiencies, business cycles, capital debates and income distribution effects, in favour of more statistics and mathematical modelling. Supporters say the expanded technical toolkit will restore the subject’s relevance to those who currently by-pass it for business studies or other social disciplines.

 

However, critics charge that narrower focus and procedural prescriptiveness are what have stifled interest, just when the spread of everyday economic problems – from widening world inequality to underfunded personal pensions – should be reviving it. A reductionist search for optimising ‘microfoundations’ neglects economies’ ‘emergent’ properties, produced by individuals’ interactions and not predictable from their actions. Economists build an unrealistic ‘micro’ picture, based on well-informed rational choices that even statistically trained subjects seem incapable of making. They thereby lose the macro picture, denying (or ascribing to state interference) such awkward phenomena as persistent unemployment and growth-rate differences, because the models point to ‘equilibrium’ and ‘convergence’.

 

In his just-published Reorienting Economics*, Dasgupta’s Cambridge nemesis and leading ‘realist’ Tony Lawson goes beyond the usual arguments about what to measure and how to model, tracing the economists’ troubles to the way they view the world. He accuses the mainstream of twisting the economy to fit mathematical analysis by treating it as a ‘closed’ mechanical system, ignoring complexities due to reflection and reaction by its constituent parts, and their need for social institutions to ster through the complexity. Economists’ search for surface ‘event regularities’, showing which policy levers to push, displaces concern for the more relevant underlying tendencies and structures, whose surface manifestations resist statistical disentanglement. Mainstreamers’ mistake, Lawson argues, is to mimic (nineteenth-century) natural scientists in ‘inducing’ general principles from superficial observation, or ‘deducing’ them from axioms, when all they can realistically do is ‘retroduce’ the deeper reality from surface effects.

 

Instead of arguing, in a classic example, whether sighting of a black swan negates the universality of white swans, realists want to re-focus on the mechanisms that generate and change swans’ colour. Many alternative views are demanding attention from the mainstream. Evolutionists emphasise the path-dependent nature of technological and industrial change. Institutionalists deny the reducibility of all social structures to individual decisionmaking and voting. ‘Austrian’ theorists point out how markets can coordinate choice by interdependent individuals with scattered and limited information, inverting the textbook depiction of fully informed and behaviourally independent individuals. ‘Post-Keynesians’ seek the return of aggregate demand to explanations of economies’ short-run cycles, and of income distribution to accounts of their long-run growth. 

 

UK calls for a rethink have found strong resonance elsewhere in Europe, notably the ‘post-autistic economics (PAE) movement’ launched on the internet by disgruntled French students in 2001. As the PAE’s Crisis in Economics** manifesto hit the press in early April, the plea for pluralism reached the ‘other’ Cambridge, with 700 Harvard students rallying behind Professor Stephen Marglin’s campaign for a broader-spectrum introductory course. Colleagues’ rejection of his eclecticism drove home the dissenters’ point..

 

Machin and Oswald speculate at the end of their 2000 study that shrinking supply will eventually cause a jump in economists’ price, until their soaring pay brings financially savvy students flocking back onto their courses. But loss of initiative to more inclusive disciplines could thwart that recovery. Non-mainstream staff and students displaced from economics faculties have often found more fertile ground in business schools and other social science departments, where methodologies snubbed by peer review still prosper in the marketplace.

 

In an accompanying survey of minority representation, David Blackaby and Jeff Frank interpreted the high proportion of expatriate staff in higher-ranked UK economics departments as confirming the UK’s entry into a global market for top economic talent. But if the commercial capture of home-grown high flyers is as widespread as the Royal Economic Society suggests, this import of labour to resolve local skill gaps owes more to the pattern of the UK’s National Health Service than football’s Premier League.

 

Economists used to joke that they had solved the unemployment problem – for economists. For much of their subject’s history, this could be done without any professional entry restriction. As chroniclers Keith Tribe and Alon Kadish have shown, pioneering courses at London and Cambridge faced a protracted struggle to attract sufficient students. Most continued to see classics, history, law or moral philosophy as firmer career foundations, or preferred to keep their elegant mathematics unsoiled by social concerns. A century on, that attitude seems to be returning. Economics that continues to sidestep reality could soon be down to economy size.

 

 

* Tony Lawson (2003) Reorienting Economics, London and New York: Routledge

** Edward Fullbrook (ed) (2003) The Crisis in Economics, London and New York: Routledge



*This article appeared in The Times Higher Education Supplement, 2 May 2003, under the title ‘Dismal Returns of Micro-Men’

 

 

Alan Shipman (alms@aol.com) is a freelance economist, affiliated lecturer in the Faculty of Social and Political Sciences, Cambridge University. His books includeThe Globalization Myth, The Market Revolution, and Transcending Transaction.

 

______________________________

SUGGESTED CITATION:
Alan Shipman, “The Disappearing Science“, post-autistic economics review, issue no. 20,  3 June 2003, article 4, http://www.paecon.net/PAEReview/issue20/Shipman20.htm